LAND REFORMS IN INDIA- DONE WITH AND THE UNFINISHED AGENDA
LAND
REFORMS IN INDIA
DONE
WITH AND THE UNFINISHED AGENDA
SUBHASH
CHANDRA GARG
Economy,
Finance and Fiscal Policy Strategy; Also, former Finance and Economic Affairs
Secretary, Government of India
Prime Minister, in his
address to the nation, on 12th May, spoke about reforms of land,
labour, liquidity and laws. Finance Minister was to spell out specific reform
proposals. She proposed three reforms- agriculture produce marketing law,
essential commodities law and another law for quality assurance in agriculture
produce. However, land reforms agenda has not been spelt out as yet.
Total built up area-
factories, roads, buildings- represent land used by non-agriculture economy.
Based on satellite surveys carried out of the entire Indian land mass, total
area occupied by buildings, land and railways, which covered all the built-up
area was only 2.04 million hectares in 2010. It is less than 1% of the land
mass of India. Agriculture Ministry reports about 25 million hectares as ‘area
under non-agricultural uses’; however, this definition covers lands under
rivers, water bodies, parks, social forestry and so on. Agriculture occupies
about 140 million hectares- about 45% of reporting land area.
Agriculture, mining and
other directly land based productive activities contribute only 20% of GDP of
India. The rest of the economy, which uses 1% of land mass, contributes 80% of
the GDP. Productivity of land use in non-agriculture and agriculture is 200:1.
India at Independence- A Poor Populous
Country with Low Per Capita Land
India, at independence,
was basically an agrarian economy with more than 60% output generated in
agriculture and more than 80% people dependent on agriculture for their
livelihood. It was also a poor country with more than 80% people living below
the poverty line. Agriculture was the principal source of government revenue
and land the main productive asset. The landowners made up India’s the wealthy
class. Peasants tilled the land but lived in poverty.
Indian population was
360 million strong in 1951. Net land area sown in 1951 was a little less than
120 million hectares out of total reporting area of about 305 million hectares.
Indians had, on an average, only .85 hectare of land per capita in 1951.
Compared to any other part of the world, Indian had a very small per capita
availability of agriculture land.
More than 82% (295
million out of total counted population of 357 million in 1951 census) Indians
lived in rural areas. Census 1951 counted 104 million Indians as
self-supporting- those who depended for their livelihood on income generated by
themselves. About 70% self-supporting persons (71 million) derived their income
from cultivation of land. Land was the principal source of livelihood for about
75% Indian households.
Real gross value added
at factor cost in agriculture, forestry, mining, and quarrying at current
prices was Rs. 5274 crores (53% of total Gross Value Added of Rs. 10036 crores.
Per capita income of 295 million people living in rural areas in 1950-51 was
only about Rs. 180.
Too many people living
in rural area dependent upon land cultivation for their livelihood earning very
low level of income was the root cause of India’s abject state of poverty at
India’s independence. Poverty, malnutrition and disease was rampant in rural
India.
India also inherited a highly
lopsided distribution of land at independence. A great majority of people, the
peasants, worked on the lands controlled by relatively fewer landlords. They
earned pittance as wages and share in produce of their back breaking work. Much
of the crop or proceeds of the crop went to landlords and the government as
revenue. Too little per capita availability of land, also unevenly distributed,
provided a fertile ground for creating sentiments of class injustice.
Land Reforms Imperative
at Independence
There were four
fundamentally disturbing situations as regards land and agriculture in British
India and even when India became independent:
First, the Government,
significantly dependent upon tax revenue from agriculture- the land revenue-
was taxing poor farmers forcing a vast majority to live life of penury. It was
universally felt that the land revenues have to be reduced drastically.
Second, the Government
collected land revenue mostly through intermediaries- the zamindars, who
exploited peasants. Rich zamindars and poor peasants demonstrated stark
inequality of India. This disturbed the conscience of everyone. There was
widespread sympathy for abolition of zamindari system and establishing direct
relationship with the state.
Third, while per capita
availability of land was low, unequal ownership and possession of land made the
matters worse socially. It was also widely felt that land was basic source of
livelihood. This called for fairer redistribution of land.
Fourth, lot of peasants
worked on others’ land as tenants. This called for conferring permanent
tenurial titles on peasants.
Indian leadership
decided to undertake three major land reforms:
First, confer ownership
and tenancy rights in land to the tillers of the land;
Second, establish
direct relationship between state and farmers by removing landlords and other
intermediaries;
Third, ensure equitable
distribution of agricultural land by imposing land ceilings and redistributing
such acquired and government surplus lands to landless.
In addition, the land
revenue was to cease as source of revenue for the governments. Instead,
agriculture was to receive more and more subsidies from the governments.
Land Reforms of
Conferring ‘Ownership’ Rights on Tillers of Land and Abolition of
Intermediaries Gets Mostly Completed in 1950s and 1960s
Two systems, defining
relationships of the tiller with the State, were prevalent primarily in India
at the time of independence.
First, the Zamindari
System in which the intermediary- the Zamindar- had considerable ownership
rights in land. The farmers had permission to till assigned lands and pay the
tax to the Zamindar, who would in turn pay a part of it to the State. These
farmers did not have either ownership or permanent tenancy in the land.
Second, under the
system called ryotwari system, there was no formal intermediary; the farmer was
in direct relationship with the State for tax payment. However, in practice,
there were numerous intermediaries, acting under different authorities granted
and assumed. The tenurial standing of the farmer was also not very clear and
coded in laws.
States started enacting
land tenancy laws in 1948. States also enacted zamindari abolition laws in
1950s. Almost all did so over a period of time. By 1960s, these seminal reforms
got implemented fairly well in the country. The legislations abolishing
zamindaris and intermediaries achieved a significant transformation of the
countryside by enlarging the base of land ownership. Tenancy laws also
succeeded in conferring permanent tenancy rights over the lands they tilled to
the peasants.
As a result of the
implementation of these laws, the ownership of nearly 40% of cultivable land
was transferred to the direct producers. Further, under the tenancy laws nearly
12.4 million tenants obtained secured rights or ownership rights over an area
of 6.16 million hectares (i.e. about 4.4% of cultivated area).
West Bengal went a step
ahead. Share-cropping was a very common arrangement in rural India. The farmer
would take land from the recorded land owner and pay a share of the produce to
the owner- the share depending on several factors like who would provide inputs
etc. West Bengal decided to convert share-cropper cultivators (called
bargadars) into permanent tenants. Approximately 1.5 million bargadars were
provided permanent tenancy in Operation Barga in West Bengal, which concluded
sometime in 1980s.
India did see the end
of Zamindari. India also witnessed tillers of land getting land recorded in
their names and giving them the ownership title.
Land Revenue Stopped
Being Source of Land Revenue
Land revenue was a
major source of tax revenue in British India. British decided to settle the
land revenue every 20/30 years. That is where the great settlement system
began. Every settlement was likely to lead to increase in land revenue payable.
Bardoli agitation was also the response to British Government decision to increase
land revenue by 20-22% in 1920s when new settlement was taken up.
Post-independence, both
land revenue and agriculture income tax were placed in the States’ list. Over
the years, land revenues, in numerous forms in which it was collected, have
been reduced to be made nominal and finally completely done away with. In some
states, farmers protested total abolition of land revenue as payment of land
revenue had become an evidence of the fact that the land continues to be in
their names.
Almost no state levies
agriculture income tax, except on plantations in some states. As land is
primarily agricultural, whatever gets reflected under the land revenue head is
largely the land conversion revenue which the states get on converting
agriculture land into non-agriculture.
Land and agriculture
incomes has stopped being a source of revenue for the governments.
Land Ceiling Reforms
were not Successful: It Took 25 Years to Build ‘Consensus’ on Land Ceiling
Land redistribution by
imposing ceiling on large landlords proved most contentious of the land
reforms. There were too many vested interests. There were three key issues
which bedevilled ceiling reforms- (a) what should the ceiling be, (b) whether
to impose it on individual or family and if on family what should the
definition of family be and (c) whether to pay compensation for acquiring land
over ceiling and what that compensation should be.
In the pre-independence
period, Congress took very conflicting policy stance on the issue of land
ceilings. After independence, several Committees had to be appointed over 25
years, which examined the matter and made incoherent recommendations. Several
states, in the meantime, enacted land ceiling legislations but with differing
objectives and results.
The first major
Committee, post-independence, the Congress Agrarian Reforms Committee appointed
in 1947 with J. C. Kumarappa as Chairman, which comprehensive recommendations
on the question of removal of intermediaries and conferring tenurial rights, did
not even make any explicit recommendation on land ceilings.
The Planning Commission
appointed Guljari Lal Nanda Panel on Land Reforms in May 1955. Nanda Panel recommended
that the family should be taken as the operative unit in land. Panel defined
family widely to consist of husband, wife and dependent sons and daughters and
grandchildren. The Penal generously recommended exclusion of several categories
of land holders from the ceiling- sugarcane farms owned by sugar factories,
orchards, plantations, special farms such as cattle breeding, dairy farms etc.,
farms in compact block, efficient farms and mechanised farm and farms with
heavy investment.
The Central Land
Reforms Committee (CLRC), constituted in August 1971, recommended ‘family’ to
include husband, wife and minor children only. CLRC also recommended an absolute
ceiling for a family of five at 54 acres. It recommended withdrawal of exemptions
in favour of mechanised farms, well managed farms etc.
A high-powered
committee (HPC), which reviewed CLRC recommendations, disagreed with CLRC on
the crucial issue of definition of family. The HPC was of the view that ceiling
should be applied to the family of five as a unit, consisting of husband, wife
and three children, whether major or minor. It recommended that if actual
members in a family were less than five, the ceiling should be reduced by a
fifth per person. A new recommendation made by the HPC proposed an allowance of
15% to be given to the landowner with land irrigated from private sources.
Diluted and Weaker Land
Ceilings Got Implemented Finally But Poorly
The Government finally released
its guidelines to the States on the question of ceiling in 1971-72. The States enacted and aligned their land
ceiling laws building with these Guidelines and new Constitutional mandate
regarding compensation.
The Guidelines proposed
that a ‘family holding’ may be considered from two aspects, namely (a) as an
operational unit, and (b) as an area of land which can yield a certain average
income. The States were delegated authority to decide whether the ceiling
should apply to individual holdings or to holdings of families, and especially
in the latter case, the basis on which the size of the family should be allowed
in the application of the ceiling.
The States, in all,
declared 2.7 million hectares land as surplus - the land found to be in excess
of land ceiling. Out of this declared surplus land, 2.3 million (87%) hectares
were taken possession of. Only 1.9 million hectares could be distributed to 5.5
million households.
The land ceiling issue
was largely forgotten after 1980s. A Committee on Land Reforms appointed by the
UPA Government in 2008 last reviewed the matter. This Committee quoted
estimates made by IAS Academy, the LBSNAA, and placed the potential of ceiling
surplus land at approximately 21 million hectares. It vigorously argued for
taking up the land ceiling agenda again but the Committee’s report did not receive
any consideration.
The Planning Commission
captured the policy flip-flop in designing and implementing land reforms most
poignantly. Its Task Force noted in its report in 1973- “in no sphere of public
activity in our country since independence has the hiatus between the precept
and practice, between policy-pronouncements and actual execution, been as great
as in the domain of land reforms.”
A Sideshow- Urban Land
Ceiling- was Badly Conceived, Failed but Left a Lot of Mess
Driven by misguided
notion that urban land prices could be controlled by acquiring excess urban
land and nobler objective of providing land for affordable housing, the Urban
Land (Ceiling and Regulation) Act was enacted in 1976. Law provided for a
specific ceiling limits for urban vacant land. The land in excess of ceiling
was to be acquired by the state governments on payment of a meagre amount. A
large number of exemptions were provided which was amenable to misuse.
This law was repealed
in 1999. About 50000 hectares of land got vested in state governments in about
20 years. Actual possession was taken for only 20000 hectares. Utilisation of
land acquired for affordable housing was almost negligible.
This was a miserable
failure. Urban land which was scarce in India became still scarcer. A vast
corruption industry grew up in getting excess urban land exempted and handing
over the excess lands in such manner that it defeated the purpose.
Requisites of Modern Indian Economy
India graduated from an
agriculture to a non-agriculture economy after industry was opened up in 1991. Non-agricultural
economy has been expanding much faster than agriculture for five decades now.
Industry requires only
a fraction of land to produce same amount of value addition. Still, land is
scare for industrial purposes. It is not available where needed. Numerous
restrictions apply on land use for industrial purposes. Services require still
less land to produce equal amount of value addition. Service economy, however,
runs on large infrastructure. It also requires lot of social infrastructure-
houses, schools, hospitals and numerous other facilities. Urbanisation is the
result of service economy.
Land is required for
construction of infrastructure and urban facilities to meet housing and other
requirements of the managers and workers of non-agricultural economy. A house
becomes an aspirational asset which lot of non-agriculture economy people find
worth making investment in. Infrastructure like roads, flyovers etc. are needed
for post-agriculture economy.
Not more than 1% of Indian
land mass is occupied by non-agriculture economic use, to produce over 80% of
GDP and providing infrastructure and housing for living of more than 1/3rd
of Indian people. The productivity of land use in industry, infrastructure,
services and urbanisation is 200 times the productivity in agriculture. It
should be no brainer that we should liberally allow transfer of land from
agriculture to non-agriculture use.
Essentially, there are
five sets of land reforms issues which constitute India’s unfinished land
reform agenda to usher India into an urban, industrial and largely service sector
economy.
First, Creation of a
National Land Record Registry.
Second, Abolition of
all restrictions on agriculture land leasing and sale.
Third, Freely
permissible conversion of agriculture land into non-agriculture use, subject
only to environmental considerations.
Fourth, Purchase and
Sale by free will to be the default mode of land transfer; acquisition under
eminent domain only for exceptional situation.
Five, Better management
of Government lands; allotment or auction of government land encroached upon.
Creation of a National Land Record
Registry
Land record system in
the country has evolved over centuries essentially to record agriculture land.
Our land record system does not recognise and record what non-agriculture use
the land has been put to. The land record system was designed to assess and
record the land revenue tax to be collected and collected from each land.
India is trying to
digitise the land records for quite some time. Currently, a Programme named
Digital India Land Records Modernisation Programme (DILRMP) is under
implementation. The Record of Right has been completed in over 90% of villages
and there are, in all, 291.10 million records of rights in the country.
There are three major
deficiencies in the DILRMP. First, it computerises the record of rights as it
exists in the states. There is no national template. There is no national or
state registry of land records. Second, the record of right records essentially
status of tenancy/ownership rights of the person over the surveyed plot of
land. It is also a static record and assignment of different rights in the
land- leasing, mortgage etc. are either not recorded or updated. Third, the
record of rights is maintained basically for agricultural land and no record of
rights for abadi plots are recorded anywhere.
Reforms in land record
system are urgently called for. A National System of Land Records should be put
in place. We should take up a 10- year Mission to complete all land records-
agricultural, residential, businesses, housing, infrastructure- recording the
type of activity the land is subject to, the ownership and other attributes.
This National Register of Land Record should be managed by a Depository Institution
and should record every transaction relating to ownership or rights in land. The
Land Register should be publicly available for information.
Reforms in Land Leasing
Will Serve Interests of Both Lessor and Tenant
As self-cultivation was
considered a nobler thing in the socialistic state of India and exploiting
absentee landlord was the arch-typical villain, policy makers decided to outlaw
agriculture land leasing in the country. Land leasing became illegal in most
parts of the country under tenancy and land revenue laws.
Such statutory
restrictions, however, could not overcome the real economy necessity of leasing
lands. Land leasing is quite rampant. The land leasing restrictions have been
relaxed in some states over the years. Andhra Pradesh passed- Andhra Pradesh
Licenced Cultivators Act in 2011. Some other States brought contract farming
through amendment in other laws. Yet, there are millions of landowners who
still do not formally lease land.
NITI Aayog constituted
an Expert Committee on Land Leasing in 2015. The Expert Committee documented
the state of land leasing laws and restrictions in the country very well. The
Committee recommended negating all the provisions in land laws of the states
banning and restricting land leasing. The Committee also proposed a new Model
Agricultural Land Leasing Act, 2016. The proposed Act protects legitimate
interests of both lessor and lessee. The Committee also recommended a standard
land leasing agreement.
The draft model law was
circulated to States. A few States enacted laws to give effect to recommended
model law. All these laws have however not come into effect as the Centre has
not provided its concurrence to such laws. Apparently, the Department of Rural
Development objected to the draft law.
Government appointed a
Group of Ministers in November 2019 to go into the question of land leasing law
again. It is not known what recommendations the GOM made. Finance Minister
announced in her budget speech 2020-21 “We propose to encourage those State governments
who undertake implementation of following model laws already issued by the
Central government: a) Model Agriculture Land Leasing Act, 2016...” Nothing has
been heard about progress made in this regard. This matter did not find mention
in the reforms announced along with stimulus package.
The enactment of Model
Agriculture Land Leasing Act is an absolute must for farmers’ welfare, growth
of agriculture and Indian economy.
In fact, the scope of
the law should be extended to allow leasing for non-agricultural purposes as
well. The agricultural land taken under leasing arrangements should not be
subject to agriculture ceiling laws. Leasing period should be left entirely at
the will of the parties to the contract. Leasing can be for one crop or for 25
years, it should not matter to the State.
Free Conversion of
Agriculture Land into Non-Agriculture Use
Agriculture yielded
revenue to the state. Land was the tax base for collecting revenue from
agriculture. The state went into very elaborate ‘settlement’ surveys of land to
determine land revenue payable on each plot of land.
Agriculture land
operates under severe restrictions. The biggest constraint is that it can be
used only for agriculture purpose. Agriculture is a very low-income yielding
business. As a result, asset value of land, as an agriculture property, is
quite depressed.
Situation changes
dramatically when agriculture land gets converted into non-agricultural land
for several reasons. There is enormous demand supply gap of non-agricultural
land as less than 1% of India’s landmass is available for use for all its
residential, commercial, infrastructure and business needs. Incomes generated
from non-agriculture use of land is also manifold as GDP produced per unit of
land is at its minimum 200 times more for non-agriculture land than agriculture
land.
Two major reasons
motivate state governments to follow highly restrictive policies to convert
lands from agriculture to non-agriculture use. First, there is a mistaken
belief that there is shortage of agriculture land and it would hurt farmers if
agriculture land is transferred to non-agriculture use. Second, the system has
not figured out how to handle the big value jump the agriculture use land
receives upon conversion in non-agriculture use. Unable to resolve these
issues, the state governments have opted for no or very low conversion as a
default policy. Rules for conversion are riddled with too much discretion with
the conversion authorities.
All these convoluted rules are a perfect recipe for
inaction and corruption.
If India were to
convert only 1-2% of its land mass into non-agriculture use, the entire demand
supply would change. Non-agriculture use land would not be as costly as it is
today. Industry, infrastructure and housing would become affordable and promote
businesses and growth of the country. It would help farmers get little more
money. Land availability for agriculture would not be affected at all.
The reform of land
conversion regime is, therefore, absolutely justified. Conversion of
agricultural land into non-agricultural use should be freely permitted. There
should not be any requirement of a state officer passing a conversion order. In
fact, the distinction that land is agricultural or non-agricultural should
disappear. The environmental, health, safety and other legitimate common
consideration are regulated by the laws which govern emissions. Pollution,
safety etc. The land, whether called agricultural use or industrial use or
infrastructure use would remain subject to these laws.
Sale Should be the Primary
Mode; Compulsory Acquisition an Exception
For all practical
purposes, the land ownership vests in the person recorded as tenant in the
record of rights and is the private property of the landholder. Private
property is normally transferable by sale and purchase contracts. Lot of
agriculture land also gets purchased and sold by private contracts.
Normal system of free
sale and purchase collapses in two situations. First, when the state needs land
for public purpose. As it is generally difficult for state authorities to
accept the price demanded by the seller or to determine right price in an
accountable and objective manner, the State does not enter into purchase and
sale contracts. Second, whenever private enterprises require large chunks of
land for an industrial, infrastructure or residential project, getting past
minority recalcitrant tenants becomes almost impossible.
As a result, larger
procurement of land for non-agricultural purposes, has been made under the land
acquisition laws. There was another real practical problem. Until converted for
non-agriculture use, the agriculture land purchased remained agricultural.
Agricultural land is subjected to ceilings. Ceilings were small. Consequently,
industry or entrepreneur could not procure agriculture land by private purchase.
Land Acquisition Act 1894 became the principal instrument of land acquisition
for public and private projects in India post-independence. As development
required good amount of agriculture land to be used for non-agriculture
purposes, Land Acquisition Act, 1894 came to be used quite frequently.
Land Acquisition Act
1894, both in design and in operation, worked against the landholder farmer.
Land could be acquired for almost any purpose as the ‘public purpose was quite
widely defined and interpreted in practice. Compensation payable was the market
value of similar land. Market value of such similar land, as recorded in
registrar’s record, was quite depressed on account of agriculture being hardly
a good value creator and the real transaction prices not being disclosed in
registration documents. Solatium offered was meagre 30%. For first 30-40 years,
the farmers literally got a pittance as compensation. As land was usually taken
possession much before the compensation was provided, lakhs of farmers were
rendered destitute.
The 2013 Law- Right to
Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and
Resettlement Act, 2013- moved the pendulum to the other extreme. Compensation
was made 4 times in rural areas and 2 times in urban areas. Such multiples hurt
more as the base price, as recorded in registrar’s office, was manipulated to
be much higher than the normal market price. Many other compensation and
assistance was mandated to be provided to not only the landowners but also
various others affected persons. Provisions of social assessments and obtaining
free consent of large number of people (70-80%) in case of projects with
private participation were made quite stringent. The process also became
impossible to navigate.
Results have been quite
disastrous. Private sector has stopped making land acquisition under the 2013
Act. The Government is making payments which are way above anything
justifiable. Land cost is making infrastructure projects of NHAI and others
quite unviable. No road projects are being built on Build, Own and Transfer
(BOT) basis. NHAI has got into debt trap.
The situation has to
change. A balance in the interests of landowners and purchasers has to be
restored. Land has to become freely available for industrialisation and
infrastructure building of the country. This is necessary to build a $10
trillion Indian economy.
2013 Law mixes up
several things. It enmeshes the environmental and social considerations of an
infrastructure or industrial project with land acquisition. It confuses the
welfare and development of the people with the compensation for land
procurement. It fails to recognise the forces at play which affect the market
prices and artificially inflates the compensation payable. It forgets
considerations of viability of the infrastructure project totally. Two
fundamental reforms are called for in the 2013 law.
First, the
applicability of the law needs to be severely limited. It should be used only
for the projects which require land for the government to produce public goods
and services only. Defence, policing, health, regulation etc. should be the
purposes for which land could be ‘acquired’. For the private projects, the
acquisition law should be used only for the situations where the private
entrepreneur is able to buy more than 80% of the land by private negotiations
but some minority landowners are unjustifiably holding up remaining land. In
such situations, the land acquisition law should be used only for determining
what is a reasonable price.
Second, all the
confusions and contradictions of the 2013 Law should be sorted out. The
environmental and social impact consideration should be made applicable to the
project, not the land acquisition. Price paid for land should be related to
market price of land plus a compensation. If the underlying market price is not
reflective of true price, the same should be objectively determined by the
acquisition officer. Other interests in the land property should be recognised
and compensated in a fair manner. All the requirements of giving jobs,
annuities etc. should be done away with.
Land Reforms for Slums
Development
Census 2011 informs
that there were 44 lakh households in slums in 2011. At 5 persons a household,
this meant over 2 crore people lived in slums in 2011. A Committee of the
Government of India estimated that India’s slum population might increase to
10.4 crore by 2018. No good estimates of land area occupied by slums are
available.
There are two basic
facts about slums.
First, all slums are
invariably on government and local authorities land. A survey estimated that
60% of slum land is government land and 40% that of local bodies.
Second, slums are almost
always inhabited by migrants. Those migrants who come to cities in search of
work and unable to find an affordable rental place to live and work from in
cities end up finding shelter in slums.
It is the economic
policies pursued by India which are responsible for creating slums. Elite urban
planning did not envisage and allow building of affordable housing and renting
places in cities at locations where such supply was needed reflected in the
location of slums. Renting as a policy for housing was totally decimated by
misconceived policy of rent control and almost impossible ejectment of tenant.
Private sector did not build affordable rentable apartments for migrants to
live in cities. The Government planners did not allow any such housing to come
up as well. Result was absolute shortage of affordable rentable houses which is
at the root of mushrooming slums on government lands.
While the slum
development programmes undertaken by central and state governments would
somewhat improve the living conditions at least in some slums, the solution,
for slums, slum dwellers and the cities, has to be found in the roots of the
problem.
First, the government
and local bodies must recognise that clearance of slums is neither feasible nor
necessary.
Second, the entire
government and local bodies land occupied under slums, minus what is required
for creating minimum infrastructure of utilities, should be, as a policy, be
used for creating affordable housing, mostly rental housing, for migrants.
Third, the slum lands,
excluding the utilities infrastructure land, should be auctioned to
cooperatives of slum dwellers and private developers for developing primarily
rental housing for migrants. As the rental housing would be developed in higher
rise buildings, which a liberal policy should allow, the existing inhabitants
should be able to get rental housing for them. The proceeds of auction can be
used for infrastructure creation and providing cash support for the
slum-dwellers.
INDIA’S UNFINISHED LAND
REFORM AGENDA
First, it is time to
move over from our present land record system of Mughal era vintage. We should
create a modern national system of land records, covering both rural and urban
areas. We need to move beyond recording only ownership and other rights only
from agricultural relationship. We should take up a National System of Land
Records to complete all land records- agricultural, residential, businesses,
housing, infrastructure- recording the type of activity the land is subject to,
the ownership and other attributes. This National Land Record should be managed
by a Depository Institution. The Land Register should be dynamic register with
every change relating to ownership or rights in land being recorded in the Land
Register, as part of the transaction itself. The Land Register should be
publicly available for information.
Second, enactment of the
draft Model Agriculture Land Leasing Act circulated by the NITI Aayog is an
absolute must for farmers’ welfare, growth of agriculture and Indian economy. It
would be advisable to widen the leasing reforms proposed in the model law. The
scope of the law should be extended to allow leasing for non-agricultural
purposes as well. The enactment of this law should be accompanied by deletion
of all restrictive provisions in respective tenancy and land revenue laws of
the states. The agricultural land taken under leasing arrangements should not
be subject to agriculture ceiling laws. Leasing period should be left entirely
at the will of the parties to the contract.
Third, non-agriculture
use of land in India in industrialisation, urbanisation and infrastructure is
very small. Less than 1% of land is used in buildings, roads and railways-
which produces entire 60% plus non-agriculture GDP. Apprehensions of
large-scale transfer of agriculture land into non-agriculture land are entirely
misplaced and misconceived. Paucity of non-agriculture land is also responsible
for excessive urban land prices. If India were to convert only 1-2% of its land
mass into non-agriculture use, the entire demand supply situation for urban
land would change. Non-agriculture use land would not be as costly as it is
today. Industry, infrastructure and housing would become affordable and promote
businesses and growth of the country. It would help farmers get little more
money. Land availability for agriculture would not be affected at all.
This calls for
fundamental reform of land conversion regime. Conversion of agricultural land
into non-agricultural use should be freely permitted. In fact, the distinction
that land is agricultural or non-agricultural should disappear. The
environmental, health, safety and other legitimate common consideration are
regulated by the laws which govern emissions, pollution, safety etc. Linking
conversion to such requirements needs to be done away with.
Fourth, the 2013 land
acquisition law- The Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land
Acquisition, Rehabilitation and Resettlement Act, 2013 needs to be thoroughly
recast and refocussed.
Two fundamental reforms
are called for in the 2013 law. First, it should be limited to only two types
of acquisitions- the government projects to produce public goods and services like
defence, policing, health, regulation etc. and private projects where more than
80% of the land has been bought by private negotiations but minority landowners
are unjustifiably holding up remaining land. In case of private purpose
acquisitions, land acquisition authority should only determine the fair price
to be paid. Second, all the confusions and contradictions of the 2013 Law
should be sorted out. The environmental and social impact consideration should
be made applicable to the project, not the land acquisition. Other interests in
the land property should be recognised and compensated in a fair manner but all
the stipulations of giving jobs, annuities etc. should be done away with.
Fifth, slums are the
result of flawed policy of not creating regulatory system and incentives for
building rental housing at appropriate locations in cities. All the lands over
which slums have come up are government and local bodies land. The government
and local bodies must recognise that clearance of slums is neither feasible nor
necessary.
To make slums habitable
places to live, entire government and local bodies land occupied under slums,
minus what is required for creating minimum infrastructure of utilities, should
be, as a policy, be used for creating affordable housing, mostly rental
housing, for migrants. Further, the slum lands, excluding the utilities infrastructure
land, be auctioned to cooperatives of slum dwellers and private developers for
developing primarily rental housing for migrants. As the rental housing would
be developed in higher rise buildings, which a liberal policy should allow, the
existing inhabitants should be able to get rental housing for them. The
proceeds of auction can be used for infrastructure creation and providing cash
support for the slum-dwellers.
These unfinished land
reforms are critical for India’s growth and for achieving any ambition of being
a high-income country in a foreseeable future. These land reforms need to be
fast tracked. These are tough reforms but absolutely necessary. If we don’t
bite the bullet, we will get into a low growth trajectory once again.
SUBHASH CHANDRA GARG
NEW DELHI 29/05/2020
Well Explained and Enlightening reading experience with so details
ReplyDeleteThanks. Hope this paper help in shaping up the land reform agenda in the country.
DeleteHi everyone are you looking for a professional binary, forex and Bitcoin broker/manager who will guide and help manage your trade and help you earn meaningful profits all within seven days contact Mr Barry Silbert now for your investment plan. For he has helped me to earn 10,250 USD just with a little investment capital and with the aid of his trading software system that brings forth good trading signals i was able to trade and cash out on time and am still trading with him, if you need his assistance on how to recover your lost investment in bitcoin/binary Contact him now on whatsaap +447508298691. or contact him on his email address Email: Barrysilbert540 @ gmail.com. [WITH MR BARRY I BELIEVE THERE ARE STILL GOOD INDIVIDUALS WHO STILL HAVE GOOD INTENTION TO OTHERS. ONCE AGAIN THANKS MR BARRY.]
ReplyDeleteExcellent information provided by you through this post. I follow all the mentioned information about LAND REFORMS IN INDIA. If you are looking to know about How to Send Money to Binance? then you don’t need to take stress as we are available here at: www.cryptowalletsupport.com
ReplyDelete