India's Unfinished Land Reform Agenda- Part II
UNFINISHED
AGENDA OF LAND REFORMS INDIA NEEDS
(Part
II of my blog on Land Reforms in India)
SUBHASH
CHANDRA GARG
(Economy,
Finance and Fiscal Policy Strategist;
Formerly
Finance and Economic Affairs Secretary, Government of India)
In this second part of
the blog, I examine and propose the land reforms which India needs for higher
growth, farmers’ welfare and greater employment.
India Graduates Past an Agricultural
Economy
India of 2020 is
radically different than India of 1950.
Although agriculture
and allied activities make up only 15% of GDP, India is self-sufficient in food
production and most other agriculture produces. Too many workers (about 20
crores as farmers and landless labourers making a little less than 50% of total
workforce) are still dependent on agriculture. They earn too little which makes
rural India the poverty trap of India. There is no way such a large number of
people can remain dependent on agriculture and India’s agriculture productivity
can rise or people dependent on agriculture for livelihood can hope to become
middle income families.
All the usable land
still remains deployed in agriculture. 140 million hectares of land remains
under plough still. There are numerous restrictions on farmers with respect to
freer use of agriculture land for agriculture purposes.
Over 160 lakh crore GDP
is generated in non-agricultural activities. Only small land mass of India-
less than 3 million hectares- is used for non-agriculture economic GDP.
Non-agriculture GDP is 35 times more productive in land use than the
agriculture GDP. Non-agriculture economy employs more than 50% of workforce as
well. It is the dynamic segment of economy for not only generating faster
growth but also employment.
Freedom to farmers to
use its agriculture land for agriculture purposes and liberalised transfer of
agriculture land for non-agriculture use constitute the thrust of present land
reform agenda.
Side Effects of First Round of Land
Reforms
First round of land
reforms- land to the tiller, abolition of intermediaries and imposition of
ceiling on agriculture land holdings- were driven by two principal
considerations.
First was the
humanitarian concern. The peasants were miserable because of low availability
of farming land, loss of their produce as they had to share a sizeable amount
of their produce with the zamindar/state and no permanent ownership/tenancy of
land. It was widely shared that farmers’ lot would improve if intermediaries
were removed, they get ownership/ permanent tenancy over the land which they
tilled and if additional land was made available by way of taking away excess
land from large farmers and allotting government land to them.
Second was the economic
logic. It was argued that farmers would invest in their land to make it more
productive if the land was owned/controlled by them. The policy makers also
believed, though it does not appear to be correct, that small holdings as
opposed to large holdings are more productive.
The State became
paternalistic and overprotective while delivering these reforms. Peasant was
considered incapable of protecting his interest. This led to widespread
side-effects.
The tenancy laws of
most states provided that the agricultural land could not be leased out even
for agriculture purpose. Some states which allowed leasing, placed so many
conditions that the leasing went out of use. Either you cultivate yourself or
keep the land fallow. This led to widespread informal land leasing
arrangements. It also discouraged development of village and cottage industry.
The SCs and STs land
owners were considered still less capable to protect their interest. Forget
leasing, they could not even sell their land, which others were permitted, to
any non-SC or ST person. This led to lands of such farmers becoming still more
discounted as such lands could be sold only without formal transfer of
ownership.
All these policies led
to agriculture remaining a low productivity enterprise. No capital investment
was made to improve the productivity of land. No contract production or
branding of agriculture produce was possible with peasants producing small
quantities of dissimilar quality products.
Population explosion
kept on fragmenting agriculture land holdings. Operational holdings which were
about 70 million in 1970 have become about 150 million in 2015. With land
holdings continuously becoming smaller and smaller and consequently more and
more uneconomic, there was very natural large-scale migration to
non-agricultural jobs. Informality in agriculture land arrangements has become
the normal order of the day.
Requisites of Post-Agriculture Indian
Economy
Non-agricultural
economy has been expanding faster.
Industry requires only
a fraction of land to produce same amount of value addition. Still, land is
scare for industrial purposes. It is not available where needed. Numerous
restrictions apply on land use for industrial purposes. Services require still
less land to produce equal amount of value addition. Service economy, however,
runs on large infrastructure. It also requires lot of social infrastructure-
houses, schools, hospitals and numerous other facilities. Urbanisation is the
result of service economy.
Land is required for
construction of infrastructure and urban facilities to meet housing and other
requirements of the managers and workers of non-agricultural economy. A house
becomes an aspirational asset which lot of non-agriculture economy people find
worth making investment in. Infrastructure like roads, flyovers etc. are needed
for post-agriculture economy.
All this, however,
require much less land than agriculture. Even today, not more than 1% of Indian
land mass is occupied by non-agriculture economic use, to produce over 80% of
GDP and providing infrastructure and housing for living of more than 1/3rd
of Indian people. The productivity of land use in industry, infrastructure,
services and urbanisation is 200 times the productivity in agriculture.
It should be no brainer
that we should liberally allow transfer of land from agriculture to
non-agriculture use. Unfortunately, there are massive misgivings about the land
required for non-agricultural use. There is a widely shared feeling that any
transfer of land from agriculture use to non-agriculture use would hurt
agriculture and farmers.
This has made transfer
of agriculture land into non-agriculture use an extremely difficult
preposition. Usable land (total land excluding forests, lakes, rivers,
mountains, defence land etc.) is agricultural by default. Transfer of land from
agricultural use to non-agriculture use is permissible only exceptionally. The
land transfer is mired in so much procedural hassles that direct purchase of
agriculture land for non-agriculture purpose and its conversion into such a
non-agriculture purpose is rarely executed successfully.
As a result, the State
stepped in and used land acquisition law, the eminent domain authority of the
state, to acquire land, in the name of public purpose, for industrial, housing
and infrastructural use. Land Acquisition law passed in 2013 made it necessary
to pay about 4-5 times the market cost of acquiring land for non-agricultural
purposes. Land acquisition through the state for non-agricultural purposes has
become a casualty of the land acquisition law.
All these have resulted
into extreme shortage of non-agriculture land making land prices go through the
roof in India. Land prices have risen to unjustifiably high levels. Land prices
are pricing out manufacturing in India now. Infrastructure creation is
suffering. The residential housing sector is also in deep trouble.
Five Land Reforms Which India Needs
Today
For faster growth and
employment creation, India needs four basic land reforms today.
First, Creation of a
National Land Record Registry.
Second, Abolition of
all restrictions on agriculture land leasing and sale.
Third, Freely
permissible conversion of agriculture land into non-agriculture use, subject
only to environmental considerations.
Fourth, Purchase and
Sale by free will to be the default mode of land transfer; acquisition under
eminent domain only for exceptional situation.
Five, Better management
of Government lands; allotment or auction of government land encroached upon.
Creation of a National Land Record
Registry
Land record system in
the country has evolved over centuries essentially to record agriculture land.
For most of the time, non-agriculture use meant only the land which was used
for living- the ‘abadi’ land. Industrial and infrastructure use, including
urban housing is of more recent origin. Our land record system does not recognise
and record what non-agriculture use the land has been put to.
Land record system was
meant to serve primarily the relationship of state and the tiller of the land.
All land in titular sense at least belonged to the State. Agriculture, for
millennia, was the producer of surplus. The land record system was designed to
assess and record the land revenue tax to be collected and collected from each
land.
Village was the lowest
administrative unit for recording ownership of land and collecting land revenue.
Land records have been maintained at the village level. Although land revenue
as a tax has ceased to be of any significance in post independent India, the
land record system essentially continues to be in the same format and system.
India is trying to
digitise the land records for quite some time. Currently, a Programme named
Digital India Land Records Modernisation Programme (DILRMP) is under
implementation. Latest data available on the Digital India Land Records
Modernisation Programme-MIS 2.0 Dashboard of the Department of Land Resources
inform that computerisation of the key land record- the Record of Rights- has
been completed in 5.91 lakh villages out of total 6.56 lakh villages. The
Record of Right has been completed in over 90% of villages. The Dashboard
further informs that there are, in all, 291.10 million records of rights in the
country. There are about 2 records of rights for 1 operational holding in the
country.
There are three major
deficiencies in the DILRMP.
First, it computerises
the record of rights as it exists in the states. There is no national template.
These records of rights are also available in local language only. As a result,
you do not have a national registry of land records.
Second, the record of
right records essentially status of tenancy/ownership rights of the person over
the surveyed plot of land. If the land has been converted into non-agriculture
use, at best, a note would be recorded in the last column of the record to that
effect. It is also a static record and assignment of different rights in the
land- leasing, mortgage etc. are either not recorded or updated. The Record of
Rights system is not a comprehensive record of ownership and other attributes
of ownership over land.
Third, the record of
rights is maintained basically for agricultural land. The urban areas or abadi
areas usually get clubbed into one or a few survey numbers. Responsibility of
maintaining record of buildings is entrusted to urban bodies. In practice,
there is no system of recognising land in non-agriculture areas (residential,
industrial and infrastructure). The record or rights therefore make up only a
part of the land parcels in the country.
It is an extremely
important and necessary for us to evolve an integrated system of land survey
and record, covering both rural and urban areas. There should be a national
template, which can provide for additional information meeting local
necessities. We need to move beyond only recording ownership and other rights
only from agricultural relationship. A National System of Land Records is
necessary and we should take up a 10- year Mission to complete all land
records- agricultural, residential, businesses, housing, infrastructure-
recording the type of activity the land is subject to, the ownership and other
attributes. This National Record should be managed by a Depository Institution.
The Land Register should be dynamic register with every change relating to
ownership or rights in land being recorded in the Land Register, as part of the
transaction itself. The Land Register should be publicly available for
information.
Restrictions on Land Leasing Led to
Development of Informal Share-Cropping Arrangements All Over the Country
As self-cultivation was considered a nobler thing in
the socialistic state of India and exploiting absentee landlord who got his
lands tilled by poor peasants was the arch-typical villain, policy makers
decided to outlaw agriculture land leasing in the country. Almost all the land
reform laws of the country either completely disallowed land leasing or made it
so conditional that the formal land leasing just could not have taken place.
Such statutory bans and restrictions, however, could
not overcome the real economy necessity of leasing lands. There were several reasons
why the agriculture lands had to be given to another farmer for cultivation.
The landowner might not in a physical state to undertake cultivation. Landowner
might take up another work or might migrate to cities or towns. Land parcel of
someone might be too small to be cultivated. A little larger scale of
operations might yield better crops. Another farmer might be more skill-full.
These factors also operated equally on the demand side.
Land leasing became an economic imperative and over
last few decades has become rampant. The land leasing restrictions have been
relaxed in some states over the years. Andhra Pradesh passed- Andhra Pradesh
Licenced Cultivators Act in 2011. Some other States brought contract farming
through amendment in other laws. Yet, there are millions of landowners who
still do not formally lease land.
Informal leasing system developed and became
widespread in India. It operates on commercial principles. The lessor and the
lessee enter into an informal agreement- commonly described as share-cropping
arrangement. The informal lessee cultivates the land and share a part of the
crop or its proceeds with the lessor- the share depending upon several factors
relating to who bears the inputs cost, type of land, etc.
Indian genius of doing right economic thing but
under informal arrangements impose several costs and have numerous bad
consequences especially for the lessee share cropper (the tenant). This has
been recognised even by the Committees which are very heavily socialistic or
left leaning.
To quote from 2008 Committee Report, appointed by
the UPA Government:
“Several research studies have pointed out that
restrictions on land leasing have reduced the welfare of poor tenants by
forcing them to enter into informal arrangements in contravention of the rules
and also by restricting the poor peoples’ access to land through leasing.
Besides, restrictive land leasing laws have discouraged the land-owners to
lease out land and take up non-farm enterprises which is vital for rural
transformation. Moreover, due to legal restrictions on land leasing, some
land-owners prefer to keep their land fallow than to lease out for fear of
losing the land in case they lease out. The lifting of ban on leasing in such
cases will result in better utilisation of the available land and labour and
also promote both farm and non-farm development by improving the large land
owners’ incentive and ability to invest. Also, legalisation of tenancy would
create additional incentive to produce more and enable them to access
institutional credit and other services.”
The Report, referring to evidence from NSSO, also
refer to the reasons why everyone, including the state, preferred the informal
land leasing or share-cropping arrangements. Again, to quote,
“Both NSSO data as well as independent field studies
show that tenancies are mostly unrecorded and based on oral agreements. This is
because of two reasons. First, the land owners do not like the names of tenants
to be recorded due to the fear that they may lose their rights. Second, the
states which have legally banned leasing out of land, do not make any efforts
to record tenancies, assuming that there is no tenancy in existence.”
Comprehensive Reform of
Land and Property Leasing Will Serve Legitimate Interests of Lessor and
Tenant
Indian policy makers,
motivated by socialistic mindset, deformed the land and property leasing
systems in the country. The Agriculture Tenancy Laws and Land Revenue Laws of
States banned or massively restricted leasing of land. Several laws imposed
severe restrictions on rent which can be collected from such leasing. Laws also
made it very difficult to remove the tenant from the land. Similar mindset was
visible on renting of buildings as well. Rent control laws made renting of
residential and commercial buildings an almost exceptional thing in India.
NITI Aayog constituted
an Expert Committee on Land Leasing in 2015. The Expert Committee documented
the state of land leasing laws and restrictions in the country, which is very well
summarised in the Report. It came to the conclusion “Most state governments
have either legally banned or imposed restrictions on agriculture land leasing.
Restrictive land leasing laws have forced tenancy to be informal, insecure and
inefficient. Informal tenants are most insecure and inefficient, as they do not
have legal sanctity and access to institutional credit, insurance and other
support services. In addition, restrictions on land leasing have reduced the
occupational mobility of many landowners who have interest and ability to take
up employment outside agriculture and yet are forced to stay in agriculture due
to the fear of losing land if the lease out and migrate. In short, the
restrictive tenancy laws have proved to be anti-growth and anti-poor even
though India’s policy makers thought it differently, while making such laws.”
The Committee
recommended negating all the provisions in land laws of the states banning and
restricting land leasing. The Committee also proposed a new Model Agricultural
Land Leasing Act, 2016. The Act is quite commercial in nature and protects
legitimate interests of both lessor and lessee. The Committee also recommended
a standard land leasing agreement.
The draft model law was
circulated to States. A few States enacted laws to give effect to recommended
model law. Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Uttar Pradesh and Uttarakhand either
passed new laws or amended their existing legislation. All these laws have
however not come into effect as the Centre has not provided its concurrence to
such laws. Apparently, the Department of Rural Development objected to the
draft law.
Government appointed a
Group of Ministers in November 2019 to go into the question of land leasing law
again. It is not known what recommendations the GOM made. Finance Minister
announced in her budget speech 2020-21 “We propose to encourage those State
governments who undertake implementation of following model laws already issued
by the Central government: a) Model Agriculture Land Leasing Act, 2016...” Nothing
has been heard about progress made in this regard. This matter did not find
mention in the reforms announced along with stimulus package.
The enactment of Model
Agriculture Land Leasing Act is an absolute must for farmers’ welfare, growth
of agriculture and Indian economy.
In fact, the leasing
reforms should be wider than proposed in the model law. The scope of the law
should be extended to allow leasing for non-agricultural purposes as well. The
enactment of this law should accompany deletion of all restrictive provisions
in respective tenancy and land revenue laws of the states. The agricultural
land taken under leasing arrangements should not be subject to agriculture
ceiling laws. Leasing period should be entirely at the will of the parties to the
contract. Leasing can be for one crop or for 25 years, it should not matter to
the State.
Habits are unlikely to
change soon even after this model law is enacted. Apprehensions of land-holders
are unlikely to go away. The law would however open a legitimate way to put
agriculture land through land leasing which would provide much needed credit
and schematic benefits to lessees. Over a period of time, the hiatus between
reality on ground and on paper would change.
Free Conversion of
Agriculture Land into Non-Agriculture Use
Agriculture yielded
revenue to the state. Land was the tax base for collecting revenue from
agriculture. Tax on agriculture was called land revenue. The state went into
very elaborate ‘settlement’ surveys of land to determine land revenue payable
on each plot of land. British conducted comprehensive land settlements every 20
years. Though land revenues ceased to be significant source of tax revenues,
yet the settlement system continues in many states still. It works more as
actual state of land surveys these days.
Agriculture land
operates under severe restrictions. The biggest constraint is that it can be
used only for agriculture purpose. Agriculture has become a very low-income
yielding business over the years. As a result, asset value of land, as an
agriculture property, is quite depressed. Whatever multiple you use for valuing
agriculture lands; it would throw up a small valuation as the basic profit
emanating from agriculture operations is quite small.
Situation changes
dramatically with respect to non-agricultural lands. There is enormous demand
supply gap of non-agricultural land. As noted above, less than 1% of India’s
landmass is available for use for all its residential, commercial,
infrastructure and business needs. Incomes generated from non-agriculture use
of land is manifold. GDP produced per unit of land is at its minimum 35 times
more for non-agriculture land than agriculture land.
Two major reasons
motivate state governments to follow highly restrictive policies to convert
lands from agriculture to non-agriculture use. First, there is a mistaken
belief that there is shortage of agriculture land and it would hurt farmers if
agriculture land is transferred to non-agriculture use. This leads to their
preference for land to remain for agricultural use only. Second, it is
difficult for the system to handle the big value jump the agriculture use land
receives upon conversion in non-agriculture use. Which non-agriculture use the
converted land would be put to? What would the difference in value upon the
converted land being put to non-agriculture use? How should the real difference
in value be captured? Should this difference go to farmers? How much government
should take share out it? And so on.
Unable to resolve these
issues, the state governments have opted for no or very low conversion as a
default policy. Conversion is an exception. The state governments want to
capture as much of the expected value increment upon conversion as possible for
themselves. Andhra Pradesh Agricultural Land (Conversion for Non-Agricultural
Purposes) Act, 2006 provides- “No agricultural land in the State shall be put
to non-agricultural purposes, without the prior payment of Conversion Tax to
Government.” This law further provides that 3% of the basic value of land
notified by the State Government would be payable as Conversion Tax.
Rules for conversion
are riddled with too much discretion with the conversion authorities. Odisha
Land Reforms Act 1960 provides that only a raiyat can apply for the conversion
of agricultural land for purposes other than agriculture and the authorised
would allow conversion only if he is satisfied that such conversion shall not
violate any master plan, improvement scheme, development plan or town planning
scheme or any condition or conditions prescribed for the purpose of dealing
with bonafide cases of such conversions.
All these convoluted
rules are perfect recipe for inaction and corruption.
Non-agriculture use is
more productive. Non-agriculture use of land is also absolutely necessary for
meeting residential, commercial and infrastructure demand of the country.
Non-residential use will not require vast agriculture areas to be converted in
non-agriculture use. If India were to convert only 1-2% of its land mass into
non-agriculture use, the entire demand supply would change. Non-agriculture use
land would not be as costly as it is today. Industry, infrastructure and
housing would become affordable and promote businesses and growth of the
country. It would help farmers get little more money. Land availability for
agriculture would not be affected at all.
The reform of land
conversion regime is, therefore, absolutely justified. Conversion of
agricultural land into non-agricultural use should be freely permitted. There
should not be any requirement of a state officer passing a conversion order. In
fact, the distinction that land is agricultural or non-agricultural should
disappear. The environmental, health, safety and other legitimate common
consideration are regulated by the laws which govern emissions. Pollution,
safety etc. The land, whether called agricultural use or industrial use or
infrastructure use would remain subject to these laws.
Purchase of Land for
Non-Agriculture Purpose: Sale Should be the Primary Mode; Compulsory
Acquisition an Exception
Agriculture land, in
legal parlance, usually belongs to the State. However, for all practical
purposes the land ownership vests in the person recorded as tenant in the
record of rights. In this sense, the agriculture land is a private property of
the landholder. Private property is normally transferable by sale and purchase
contracts. Lot of agriculture land also gets purchased and sold by such private
contracts. The sale gets recorded by the registrar and land is mutated in the
name of buyer by the land revenue system. The land remains agricultural land in
the record owned by the transferee.
Normal system of free
sale and purchase collapses in two situations. First, when the state needs land
for public purpose. The State is powerful and relationship between the State
and small landholders is grossly unequal. More than that, it is generally
difficult for state authorities to accept the price demanded by the seller and
extremely determine, in an accountable and objective manner, right price.
Consequently, barring exceptions, State does not enter into purchase and sale
contracts. Second, whenever private enterprises require large chunks of land
for an industrial, infrastructure or residential project, dealing with numerous
small holders subjected to restrictive provisions like SC land holder cannot
sell to non-SC land holder or the land cannot be converted to non-agriculture
use etc. under various laws makes private purchase and sale a completely messy
affair.
As a result, larger procurement
of land for non-agricultural purposes, has been made under the land acquisition
laws. There was another real practical problem. Until converted for
non-agriculture use, the agriculture land purchased remained agricultural.
Agricultural land is subjected to ceilings. Ceilings were small. Consequently,
industry or entrepreneur could not procure agriculture land by private purpose.
Land Acquisition Act 1894 became the principal instrument of land acquisition
for public and private projects in India post-independence. As development
required good amount of agriculture land to be used for non-agriculture
purposes, Land Acquisition Act, 1894 came to be used quite frequently.
Land Acquisition Act
1894, both in design and in operation, worked against the landholder farmer.
Land could be acquired for almost any purpose as the ‘public purpose was quite
widely defined and interpreted in practice. Compensation payable was the market
value of similar land. Market value of such similar land, as recorded in
registrar’s record, was quite depressed on account of agriculture being hardly
a good value creator and the real transaction prices not being disclosed in
registration documents. Solatium offered was meagre 30%. For first 30-40 years,
the farmers literally got a pittance as compensation. As land was usually taken
possession much before the compensation was provided, lakhs of farmers were
rendered destitute.
Lands which private
sector got out of acquired land produced enormous profits as the value of
non-agriculture use such land was put to was much higher. Lot of intermediaries
also saw the opportunity. Whenever there was a proposal of land acquisition,
some functionaries would get wind of it, buy lands and record the same at high
rates and rip the cream off. Farmers also got wiser but not as much. There was
still lot of unfairness as regards farmers at the turn of century.
The 2013 Law- Right to
Fair Compensation and Transparency in Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and
Resettlement Act, 2013- moved the pendulum to the other extreme. Compensation
was made 4 times in rural areas and 2 times in urban areas. Such multiples hurt
more as the base price as recorded in registrar’s office was manipulated to be
much higher than the normal market price. So many other compensation and
assistance was mandated to be provided to not only the landowners but also
various others affected persons. Provisions of social assessments and obtaining
free consent of large number of people (70-80%) in case of projects with
private participation were made quite stringent. The process also became
impossible to navigate.
Result was quite
foregone. Private sector stopped making land acquisition under the 2013 Act. The
Government is making payments which are way above anything justifiable. Even
projects like NHAI Road Projects, which are exempt from some of the procedural
provisions like consent, are paying massive amounts as land compensation.
Paying Rs. 10 crore per acre for NHAI projects is becoming normal. Land makes
up 50% of the cost of road project. Road building has become an unviable
preposition. No road projects are built on Build, Own and Transfer (BOT) basis.
The Government tried to
roll back some provisions- prior consent and social impact assessment- in five
types of acquisition- projects vital for national security or defence, rural
infrastructure projects, affordable housing and housing for the poor,
industrial corridors and infrastructure, including social infrastructure
projects. The 2015 Amendment Bill could not get through Rajya Sabha. The
Government also virtually abandoned the effort. Scene shifted to States.
Five-six States have enacted the provisions of the central amendment law by
taking consent of the central government.
Irreparable damage,
however, is done. Urbanisation, industrialisation and infrastructure building
in the country has collapsed. Capital expenditure is constantly coming down.
Infrastructure in private sector has become quite a big casualty.
The situation has to
change. A balance in the interests of landowners and purchasers has to be
restored. Land has to become freely available for industrialisation and
infrastructure building of the country. This is necessary to build a $10
trillion Indian economy.
2013 Law mixes up
several things. It enmeshes the environmental and social considerations of an
infrastructure or industrial project with land acquisition. It confuses the
welfare and development of the people with the compensation for land
procurement. It fails to recognise the forces at play which affect the market
prices and artificially inflates the compensation payable. It forgets
considerations of viability of the infrastructure project totally.
Two fundamental reforms
are called for in the 2013 law.
First, the
applicability of the law needs to be severely limited. It should be used only
for the projects which require land for the government to produce public goods
and services only. Defence, policing, health, regulation etc. should be the
purposes for which land could be ‘acquired’. The 2013 Law extends the liability
to provide for Relief and Rehabilitation package even for purely private
purchase of land through private negotiations if the land involved is more than
the limit prescribed by the Government. These provisions need to be simply
dropped. For the private projects, the acquisition law should be used only for
the situation where the private entrepreneur is able to buy more than 80% of
the land by private negotiations but some minority landowners are unjustifiably
holding up remaining land. In such situation, the land acquisition law should
be used only for determining what is a reasonable price.
Second, all the
confusions and contradictions of the 2013 Law should be sorted out. The
environmental and social impact consideration should be made applicable to the
project, not the land acquisition. Price paid for land should be related to
market price of land plus a compensation. If the underlying market price is not
reflective of true price, the same should be objectively determined by the
acquisition officer. Other interests in the land property should be recognised
and compensated in a fair manner. All the requirements of giving jobs,
annuities etc. should be done away with.
Land for
industrialisation, infrastructure, housing and other private non-agriculture
purposes should become a private transaction. Land acquisition law should be
used only for the limited purposes.
Land Reforms for Slums
Development
Census 2011 informs that
there were 44 lakh households in slums in 2011. At 5 persons a household, this
meant over 2 crore people lived in slums in 2011. A Committee of the Government
of India estimated that India’s slum population might increase to 10.4 crore by
2018. No good estimates of land area occupied by slums are available.
The Government has
taken up numerous programmes to improve housing and basic facilities for slum
dwellers. There have also been some programmes taken by state governments for
‘regularising’ possession of slum-dwellers, including providing some title to
the land as well. Slums, however, continue to grow. Current migrants’ crisis
unleased by economic lockdown imposed to contain Covid-19 exposed miserable
conditions of slum dwellers and the fragility of their connection to the slums.
There are two basic
facts about slums.
First, all slums are
invariably on government and local authorities land. A survey estimated that
60% of slum land is government land and 40% that of local bodies.
Second, slums are almost
always inhabited by migrants. Those migrants who come to cities in search of
work and unable to find an affordable rental place to live and work from in
cities end up finding shelter in slums.
As slums are ab-initio
illegal in nature, the utilities have always been reluctant to provide basic
facilities like water, electricity and roads in slums. In fact, there was a
naïve belief that if these facilities are not provided, the slums will
disappear. In last three decades, the policy makers accepted the hard reality
that the slum-dwellers and the slums were not going anywhere.
A number of slum
development programme have been launched by the central government and state
governments to improve living conditions in slums. Some programme have also
been launched to improve housing in the slums. Some programmes included
granting tenements of small sizes to the occupants of slums.
These programmes have
not made much difference. Slums continue to increase. Slum-dwellers continue to
increase. Some estimates say that about 10% of India’s population would be
living in slums in not so distant future.
It is the economic
policies pursued by India which are responsible for creating slums. Elite urban
planning did not envisage and allow building of affordable housing and renting
places in cities at locations where such supply was needed reflected in the
location of slums. Renting as a policy for housing was totally decimated by
misconceived policy of rent control and almost impossible ejectment of tenant.
Private sector did not
build affordable rentable apartments for migrants to live in cities. The
Government planners did not allow any such housing to come up as well. Result
was absolute shortage of affordable rentable houses which is at the root of
mushrooming slums on government lands.
While the slum
development programmes undertaken by central and state governments would
somewhat improve the living conditions at least in some slums, the solution,
for slums, slum dwellers and the cities, has to be found in the roots of the
problem.
First, the government
and local bodies must recognise that clearance of slums is neither feasible nor
necessary.
Second, the entire
government and local bodies land occupied under slums, minus what is required
for creating minimum infrastructure of utilities, should be, as a policy, be
used for creating affordable housing, mostly rental housing, for migrants.
Third, the slum lands,
excluding the utilities infrastructure land, should be auctioned to
cooperatives of slum dwellers and private developers for developing primarily
rental housing for migrants. As the rental housing would be developed in higher
rise buildings, which a liberal policy should allow, the existing inhabitants
should be able to get rental housing for them. The proceeds of auction can be
used for infrastructure creation and providing cash support for the
slum-dwellers.
Slums cannot be wished
away. These are the result of a particular set of policies followed. A
different set of polices can convert slums into inhabitable and healthier
places to live and work. Slum-dwellers provides significant services to the
inhabitants of cities. They can serve the cities better if they have comfort of
living in good conditions.
CONCLUSION
India’s Unfinished Land
Reform Agenda
First,
it is time to move over from our present land record system of Mughal era
vintage. We should create a modern national system of land records, covering
both rural and urban areas. We need to move beyond recording only ownership and
other rights only from agricultural relationship. We should take up a National
System of Land Records to complete all land records- agricultural, residential,
businesses, housing, infrastructure- recording the type of activity the land is
subject to, the ownership and other attributes. This National Land Record
should be managed by a Depository Institution. The Land Register should be
dynamic register with every change relating to ownership or rights in land
being recorded in the Land Register, as part of the transaction itself. The
Land Register should be publicly available for information.
Second,
enactment of the draft Model Agriculture Land Leasing Act circulated by the
NITI Aayog is an absolute must for farmers’ welfare, growth of agriculture and
Indian economy. It would be advisable to widen the leasing reforms proposed in
the model law. The scope of the law should be extended to allow leasing for
non-agricultural purposes as well. The enactment of this law should be
accompanied by deletion of all restrictive provisions in respective tenancy and
land revenue laws of the states. The agricultural land taken under leasing
arrangements should not be subject to agriculture ceiling laws. Leasing period
should be left entirely at the will of the parties to the contract.
Third,
non-agriculture use of land in India in industrialisation, urbanisation and
infrastructure is very small. Less than 1% of land is used in buildings, roads
and railways- which produces entire 60% plus non-agriculture GDP. Apprehensions
of large-scale transfer of agriculture land into non-agriculture land are
entirely misplaced and misconceived. Paucity of non-agriculture land is also
responsible for excessive urban land prices. If India were to convert only 1-2%
of its land mass into non-agriculture use, the entire demand supply situation
for urban land would change. Non-agriculture use land would not be as costly as
it is today. Industry, infrastructure and housing would become affordable and
promote businesses and growth of the country. It would help farmers get little
more money. Land availability for agriculture would not be affected at all.
This calls for
fundamental reform of land conversion regime. Conversion of agricultural land
into non-agricultural use should be freely permitted. In fact, the distinction
that land is agricultural or non-agricultural should disappear. The
environmental, health, safety and other legitimate common consideration are
regulated by the laws which govern emissions, pollution, safety etc. Linking
conversion to such requirements needs to be done away with.
Fourth,
the 2013 land acquisition law- The Right to Fair Compensation and Transparency
in Land Acquisition, Rehabilitation and Resettlement Act, 2013 needs to be
thoroughly recast and refocused.
The 2013 Law mixes up
several things. It enmeshes the environmental and social considerations of an
infrastructure or industrial project with land acquisition. It seeks to achieve
welfare and development of people from the compensation for land procurement.
It disregards the principle of market price and artificially inflates the
compensation payable. It ignores considerations of viability of the
infrastructure projects totally.
Two fundamental reforms
are called for in the 2013 law. First, it should be limited to only two types
of acquisitions- the government projects to produce public goods and services
like defence, policing, health, regulation etc. and private projects where more
than 80% of the land has been bought by private negotiations but minority
landowners are unjustifiably holding up remaining land. In case of private
purpose acquisitions, land acquisition authority should only determine the fair
price to be paid. Second, all the confusions and contradictions of the 2013 Law
should be sorted out. The environmental and social impact consideration should
be made applicable to the project, not the land acquisition. Other interests in
the land property should be recognised and compensated in a fair manner but all
the stipulations of giving jobs, annuities etc. should be done away with.
Fifth,
slums are the result of flawed policy of not creating regulatory system and
incentives for building rental housing at appropriate locations in cities. All
the lands over which slums have come up are government and local bodies land.
The government and local bodies must recognise that clearance of slums is
neither feasible nor necessary.
To make slums habitable
places to live, entire government and local bodies land occupied under slums,
minus what is required for creating minimum infrastructure of utilities, should
be, as a policy, be used for creating affordable housing, mostly rental
housing, for migrants. Further, the slum lands, excluding the utilities
infrastructure land, be auctioned to cooperatives of slum dwellers and private
developers for developing primarily rental housing for migrants. As the rental
housing would be developed in higher rise buildings, which a liberal policy
should allow, the existing inhabitants should be able to get rental housing for
them. The proceeds of auction can be used for infrastructure creation and
providing cash support for the slum-dwellers.
SUBHASH CHANDRA GARG
NEW DELHI 26/05/2020
Hi everyone are you looking for a professional binary, forex and Bitcoin broker/manager who will guide and help manage your trade and help you earn meaningful profits all within seven days contact Mr Barry Silbert now for your investment plan. For he has helped me to earn 10,250 USD just with a little investment capital and with the aid of his trading software system that brings forth good trading signals i was able to trade and cash out on time and am still trading with him, if you need his assistance on how to recover your lost investment in bitcoin/binary Contact him now on whatsaap +447508298691. or contact him on his email address Email: Barrysilbert540 @ gmail.com. [WITH MR BARRY I BELIEVE THERE ARE STILL GOOD INDIVIDUALS WHO STILL HAVE GOOD INTENTION TO OTHERS. ONCE AGAIN THANKS MR BARRY.]
ReplyDeleteExcellent information provided by you through this post. I follow all the mentioned information about Land Reform Agenda. If you are looking to know about How to Send Money to Binance? then you don’t need to take stress as we are available here at: www.cryptowalletsupport.com
ReplyDeleteHello
ReplyDeleteWe are professional traders, earning on forex and binary for investors weekly, will love to tell you all more about our investment platform where you can invest funds as little as $500 and start earning $5,500 weekly, alot of people has benefited from this investment offer before and during this convid-19 virus, if you passing through financial difficulties due to this coronavirus and you need help paying bills simply choose a suitable investment plan for yourself and start making profit weekly $500 to earn $5,000 in 7 days
$1000 to earn $10000 in 7 days
$5000 to earn $50000 in 7 days To Start your investment now contact Via email...(paytondyian699@gmail.com)